Introduction Though initially convened to fix the Articles of Confederation in 1787, the Constitutional Convention ended up creating an entirely new style of government under the Constitution. One of the items on the agenda was to devise how to elect the president, and after different proposals and amendments were brought to the table and voted on, the Electoral College of 1787 was born. Two hundred forty-four years and forty-six presidents later, the Electoral College still stands as the method by which the American president is selected. The Electoral College serves as an indirect method of voting, as the people vote for a group of electors who go on to vote for president, rather than voting for the president directly. While it was amended in 1803 (the Twelfth Amendment) and 1960 (the Twenty-Third Amendment) and states have made their own changes as time has gone on, the system has largely stayed the same. The biggest change since the Jeffersonians passed and ratified the Twelfth Amendment was the move away from majority rule (when a candidate for office receives more than 50.00% of the vote) to plurality winner- take-all (when a presidential candidate wins 50.00% or less of the vote in a state and receives 100% of electoral votes offered by that state).The debate over reforming or abolishing the Electoral College resurfaced with the 2000 and 2016 presidential elections, as the winner of the popular vote lost the electoral vote and thus the presidency. The Electoral College system has largely stayed the same since its inception. U.S. Const. art. II, §1, cl. 2-4 lays out how the original version of the Electoral College functioned. Under the original system, each state would appoint their allotted electors under whatever system they choose, with each state’s allotment being equal to the 1 number of U.S. Senators and U.S. Representatives they had in Congress (meaning every state had at minimum three electors). Some states utilized legislative appointments, others direct election, others used hybrid models. On whichever day of the year that Congress determined, the electors for each state would assemble in their states and would cast their vote for president, with only one Constitutional requirement: one of their two votes had to go to someone that was not from the same state as themselves. So, an elector in Pennsylvania was constitutionally required to vote for someone who was not from Pennsylvania. Each state was to certify and seal their electors’ votes and transmit their official votes to the President of the Senate, who would count the electoral votes in the presence of the U.S. Senate and U.S. House of Representatives, and whomever won the majority of electoral votes would become president. If no candidate received the majority of votes, the U.S. House would vote for president, and the winner would have to win the majority of state delegations. Whomever came in second in the House or among electors would become vice president. The states also decide how to allocate their electoral votes. Forty-eight states plus Washington, D.C. use a plurality winner-take-all model, while two states use a congressional district model. Under the plurality winner-take-all model, as defined earlier, a presidential candidate receives all of the electoral votes from a state without winning an absolute majority (50.01%) of the vote. For example, if a hypothetical Democratic nominee won 47.46% of the vote and a hypothetical Republican nominee won 48.18% of vote in Pennsylvania, despite the margin being so close (less than one point different), the Republican nominee would win all twenty electoral votes. Maine and Nebraska allocate their electoral votes by congressional districts and statewide 2 popular vote rather than utilizing the plurality winner-take-all method. Under this model, the candidate who wins the popular vote in each congressional district wins one electoral vote, and then whichever candidate wins the statewide popular vote receives the final two electoral votes. For example, a Democrat and a Republican both won one congressional district in the state of Maine, so they received one electoral vote each. The Democrat, however, won the statewide popular vote so they received the last two electoral votes, resulting in the Democrat receiving three votes and the Republican receiving one vote. While this system has largely worked throughout American history, there are a handful of elections where issues arose surrounding who won versus who allegedly should have won. In 1800, Thomas Jefferson and Aaron Burr, both DemocraticRepublicans, tied with seventy-three electoral votes, meaning the U.S. House for the first time had to vote for president. They ran into another problem here: votes for president were recorded over thirty times before Jefferson eventually won the requisite nine states to become president (Schropp 2010). This chaotic election set the stage for the passage and ratification of the Twelfth Amendment, creating the Electoral College of 1803, which still stands today. Under the newly ratified amendment, the vote for president and vice president were separate, and thus candidates would run as a ticket for president and vice president rather than separately as presidential candidates. At the state level, electors had to be elected by majority vote, whether by direct election by the people or by the legislature. The Jeffersonians believed that in order to receive a mandate, a president had to win a compound majority-of-majorities. The idea was that they would win the majority of the popular vote in the majority of the states to win the 3 majority of electoral votes, and only then would a president actually have a mandate in office. They also believed that electors needed to win majority support, whether it be from legislative appointment or direct election, in order to be an elector for their state. To accomplish this, states had run-off procedures to ensure that all electors had majority support. For example, New Hampshire in the very first election had their electors chosen by statewide popular vote. This frequently meant that candidates did not receive majority support. To ensure electors had majority support, the legislature received the names of the top two vote getters and chose between them, ensuring that their electors received majority support (Foley 2020). The presidential election of 1824 was the first election in which the popular vote was counted, and it happens to be the next time the electoral system broke down. In 1824, Andrew Jackson received more popular votes and electoral votes than did rivals John Quincy Adams, William Crawford, and Henry Clay. Jackson, however, did not receive enough electoral votes to win the White House, thus resulting in a run-off in the U.S. House between himself and Adams, as only the top two contenders are passed along to be voted on by the House. In the runoff, John Quincy Adams won and thus became president (Ratcliffe 2014). This sparked backlash from Jackson himself, who subsequently launched a four-year campaign for president for the 1828 election, and amongst his supporters. In the years leading up to the next presidential election, states began changing the rules for appointing electors, making it so electors only had to win a plurality of the votes. In a plurality, a candidate wins the most votes but fails to win the majority of votes (they receive 50.00% or less of the vote). In 1828, Jackson coasted to victory over incumbent President Adams, winning 178 electoral votes. 4 There were four more elections where the system broke down in some way. In 1876, Republican Rutherford B. Hayes faced off against Democrat Samuel Tilden. While Tilden won the popular vote and was winning in the electoral vote, the votes in three southern states (Florida, Louisiana, and South Carolina) were being challenged and thus, their electoral votes had not been awarded, leaving Tilden one vote shy of winning the electoral vote. With the Compromise of 1877, the remaining votes were awarded to Hayes, and thus he won the White House despite losing the popular vote (Issacharoff 2005). The presidential elections in 1888, 2000, and 2016 all turn out in similar fashions (though the election in 2000 required the intervention of the U.S. Supreme Court in the case Bush v. Gore). In all three, the winner of the popular vote lost the electoral vote, albeit by varying margins, with Democrat Hillary Clinton’s popular vote margin of victory being the largest in American history (Weinschenk and Panagopoulos 2018). Each electoral problem in some way sparked and added to the debate over whether or not the United States should continue with the Electoral College, whether it should be abolished, or whether it should be reformed. The Electoral College has also been discussed as being a possible reason for the United States lagging behind other western democracies in terms of voter turnout. Voter turnout in American elections is another problem being studied by political scientists. While participation is slightly higher in presidential elections than in midterm elections, the U.S. still has low turnout relative to international standards. In 2016, only 55.72% of age-eligible (population above the legal voting age) Americans cast a ballot, compared to 88.02% in Sweden in 2018 and 69.11% in Germany in 2017 (DeSilver 2020). In the 1960 presidential election, turnout was approximately 64%, the 5 highest to that point since 1900 (Nardulli, Dalager, and Greco, 1996). The voter turnout problem will be discussed further in the literature review section. In this paper, I will explore different proposals for reforming and abolishing the Electoral College. Utilizing survey research, I will look at how the 2020 election result would have been different under these proposed reforms. Finally, I will also explore the issue of voter turnout in American presidential elections and utilizing a survey, see if electoral reform would have any effect on voter turnout. I hypothesize that the 2020 election outcome would not differ under alternative election systems. I also hypothesize that electoral reform would increase voter turnout and that respondents would prefer the national popular vote. Literature Review The literature discussing the Electoral College and the debate over the method used to elect the president all seems to rest on the same overall argument: that the winner should reflect the will of the voters and states. While the overall argument typically revolves around this idea, there tends to be three sides in the debate. The first side argues that the United States should stay with the Electoral College as it operates today with no changes/reforms. The second side argues that the United States should abolish the Electoral College altogether and implement a national popular vote system. Though not a part of the main debate, the third side argues in favor of maintaining the Electoral College but reforming it and changing how electoral votes are awarded to candidates in presidential contests. Proposed reforms to the current system include implementing a national popular vote, utilizing proportional allocation of electoral votes, implementing the congressional district model nationwide, ranked choice voting, 6 approval voting, and range (score) voting. These debates over the future of the Electoral College have raged for decades and the Electoral College has been the subject of more proposed amendments than any other provision of the U.S. Constitution (Richie and Levien 2013; Drake 2013). As mentioned previously, it was successfully amended twice (the Twelfth and Twenty-Third Amendments), however the changes that have been seen have largely been at the state level. While not perfect, the Electoral College has its advantages and disadvantages. When discussing electoral reforms and models, Turner (2005) argues that any presidential election system should encourage broad electoral coalitions, stimulate citizen interest and turnout, produce a president who can govern, strengthen the two- party system, discourage fraud and be relatively neutral. The first side of the debate argues in favor of maintaining the Electoral College model that is currently used. Under this system, the winner of the popular vote in each state gets all of the electoral votes up for grabs (with the exception of Maine and Nebraska). Some scholars have found that support for this method of presidential election is more fluid than people generally believe it to be. Utilizing Bush and Kerry voters, Aldrich, Reifler, and Munger (2014) found that voters support for the current “winner-take-all” Electoral College method is strongest when they feel that their preferred candidate will win their state. Support for reform, specifically for the proportional method, rises when they feel that a different candidate is going to win their state. They found that four variables influenced voters’ support for the status quo or reform as (1) which candidate one supports, (2) which candidate they think will win the election under the current apportionment model, (3) preferences for abolishing the Electoral College in favor of the popular vote winter, and (4) statistical 7 interactions between these variables. Cain, Basciano, and Cain (2007) argued that being that the goal of eliminating the Electoral College is to ensure the winner more accurately reflects the will of the voters, abolishing the status quo is contrary to that goal. Their research found that eliminating the current Electoral College model risks having an incorrect result and that the Electoral College is a safeguard to prevent that incorrect result from occurring. They also found that the modern Electoral College offers some advantages that a direct popular vote methodology would not. According to Pavia (2011), supporters of the current Electoral College focus their support on seven ideas, (1) it requires a distribution of popular support to be president, (2) maintains the federal character of the country and separation of powers, (3) maintains stability by encouraging the two-party system, (4) enhances the status and integration into the system of minority groups, (5) isolates election problems, (6) reduces turnout disparities among states, and (7) prevents heavy concentrations of power in larger states. The second side of the debate fights in favor of abolishing the Electoral College and establishing a national popular vote system of voting for president, meaning that whichever candidate wins the most votes nationwide would win the presidential election. This side argues that the Electoral College produces results that are not representative of the will of voters and of the people. Karp and Tolbert (2010) argue that support for reforming presidential elections is shaped by both long and short-term forces. They claim that those on the side that lost are more likely to change their opinion on reform and favor a change in the status quo. They also argue that when it comes to 8 reform, people are more likely to support electoral reform when they live in smallpopulation states that feel unimportant in the electoral cycle and outcome. People are more likely to oppose reform when they live in a larger-population state that feels important in electoral cycles and outcomes, however, they are more open to reform if their state is later in the nominating process. They also predict that voters that live in highly influential states (determined by timing of primary or battleground status) would be less supportive of reform because they would stand to lose electoral influence and give smaller, less influential states more influence and power in the electoral process. Florey (2017) argues that there are three mechanisms, (1) the two-vote bonus, (2) population-based allocation, and (3) winner-take-all award of each states’ votes, that the modern Electoral College has that gives it the ability to produce results that would differ from a national popular vote. She argues that mechanism #3 is the least defensible and most harmful because its introduction to the electoral system was done at the state level as a result of partisan jockeying instead of as a result of debate and compromise. According to Pavia (2011), opponents of the current Electoral College focus on four main points, (1) it can elect a minority president, (2) faithless electors are possible, (3) it could possibly depress voter turnout, and (4) it fails to reflect national popular will. Fon (2004) also makes two observations critical to the opposition of the current model. He observes that there may not be a consistent relationship between the popular vote margin and the electoral vote margin, and that there might not be a relationship between the outcome of the current Electoral College system and the outcome of the national popular vote. Richie and Levien (2013) cite FairVote’s attention index in opposing the Electoral College. The attention index “measures 9 campaign attention relative to the average attention a state would have received if campaigns had spent money and allocated numbers of candidate events based only on population.” In this index, a score of 1.0 indicates that a state was treated equally relative to population, while a score over 1.0 indicates more attention and less than 1.0 indicates less attention. They found that only nine states had indices over 1.0, while the other forty-two states (plus Washington, D.C.) received a score of less than 1.0. While electoral controversies have ignited the movement pushing for a constitutional amendment to abolish the Electoral College in favor of the popular vote, they have also inspired a coalition of states to come together to propose an interstate compact known as the National Popular Vote Interstate Compact (NPV). Under this compact, the member states would award their electoral votes to whomever wins the nationwide popular vote, regardless of which candidate wins each statewide popular vote. The NPV is activated once enough states join that their collective electoral vote total is the majority of electoral votes, meaning that it will be activated upon enough states joining so that their collective total of electoral votes is equal to at minimum 270 out of 538. 270 is currently the majority of votes needed to win the presidency. Should the number of seats in the Senate and/or House change, the number of electoral votes required to win will also change so that it is the majority of possible electoral votes. There is, however, debate over the constitutionality of the compact and whether it actually could be activated once the requisite number of electoral votes is achieved. U.S. Const. art. I, §10, cl. 3 states that “No state shall, without the consent of Congress... enter into any agreement or compact with another state ” This clause, 10 known as the Compact Clause, is used by opponents of the NPV as reason why it will be difficult to activate without congressional approval. That being said, however, Drake (2013), utilizing an examination of Supreme Court decisions, argues that it would be unconstitutional for Congress to grant approval of the NPV for two reasons, (1) the Constitution explicitly states that each state gets to decide on the manner that will be used for selecting presidential electors and (2) because the Electoral College is an institution created and mandated by the Constitution, Congress thus cannot sidestep it via statutory act. His overall argument is that based on established Supreme Court decisions, the NPV must be submitted to Congress for approval prior to implementation, but that Congress cannot constitutionally grant approval of the compact, leaving it unable to be implemented. Richie and Levien (2013) present two main arguments in support of states’ ability to enter into such a compact. Their first argument is that states get to decide how to award their electoral votes, which the Supreme Court characterized as “exclusive and plenary” in the 1892 McPherson v. Blacker decision. Their second argument is that states have the constitutional right to create and engage in binding interstate compacts. They also argue that the NPV is the best way forward for electoral reform as it should result in every vote counting the same and the attention index would eventually be close to 1.0 for every state. The third side of the debate, which gets significantly less attention than the first two sides, focuses on implementing new reforms to the functionality of the Electoral College or implementing different approaches to voting for president. More specifically, proponents on this side either want to see electoral votes allocated using a method other than winner-take-all, or they want to see the implementation of a new 11 electoral system altogether but are opposed to the national popular vote method. There are a variety of different voting systems that have been explored by political scientists and mathematicians and that have been proposed as possible alternatives, including the congressional district model, proportional allocation, ranked choice voting, approval voting, and range (score) voting. In 1972 and 1991, respectively, Maine and Nebraska reformed how they allocate their electoral votes. Instead of utilizing the plurality winner-take-all rules that the other forty-eight states and the District of Columbia use, they allocate their electoral votes based on who wins in each congressional district and who wins statewide. Introducing this method of electoral allocation nationwide has also been a topic of discussion. Fon (2004), using theoretical states, calculates that this system of vote allocation has the ability to reflect voter preferences better at the state level, though if a state has at least seven electors, the statewide winner may still lose the state electoral vote. This phenomenon could occur because candidate A could win one congressional district and the statewide popular vote, which would translate to three electoral votes. If candidate B won a plurality in the other four congressional districts, that would result in candidate B winning four electoral votes to candidate A’s three electoral votes. This means that that under the congressional district model, it is possible for the statewide winner to still lose the state in the final tally. Richie and Levien (2013) argue that the Maine-Nebraska congressional district model is “indefensible” from the perspectives of partisan balance and political equality because most districts are lopsided in favor of one party and that this method would actually result in an increase in the number of elections where candidates win the electoral vote while losing the national popular vote. 12 Turner (2005) thoroughly examines this electoral system and looks at the efficiency and accuracy of the system, and how this model would impact presidential campaign strategy and the president’s ability to govern. He argues that the congressional district model reduces the winner- take-all distortion and produces a more accurate reflection of the preference of voters. He also notes how the district method would then also introduce what is known as “spillover campaigning” into the system on a broader scale. In spillover campaigning, commercials that are designed for battleground districts also get shown in non-targeted districts as a result of media markets overlapping congressional districts. An analysis of this phenomenon under the district system in the 2000 election was done in Texas and found that as a result of spillover campaigning from competitive districts in Texas and New Mexico, “voters in twenty-seven of the thirty-one districts would likely experience at least some presidential campaign advertising.” In 2000, Texas had only four competitive districts that would have seen significant advertising. An additional alternative framework that has been proposed for reforming the Electoral College is to allocate electoral votes using a proportional model, of which there are various kinds. The first model, which is used to see how the 2020 election outcome would differ, simply divides the number of electoral votes from each state based on the popular vote shares in each using only whole numbers. So, for example, in the 2016 election, Democrat Hillary Clinton won 47.46% of the vote in Pennsylvania (which has twenty electoral votes), while Republican Donald Trump won 48.18% of the vote (FEC 2017). Under this model, Clinton would receive 47.46% of the electoral vote (calculates to nine electoral votes to the nearest whole number), and Trump 13 would receive 48.18% of the electoral vote (calculates to ten electoral votes to the nearest whole number). This is known as integral proportional allocation, where the slate of electors is split roughly in proportion to the state’s popular vote with the winner of the popular vote receiving a favorable adjustment, with the electoral count awarded to each candidate always being a whole number (Fon 2004). Fon (2004) proposes one other model of proportional allocation: perfect proportion. Under perfect proportional allocation, decimals and fractions would be used to perfectly align the electoral votes in each state based upon their percentage of the electoral vote. This means that if a state has N electors and candidate A receives α% of the popular vote, then the number of electoral votes awarded to candidate A is equal to α% times N, resulting in electoral votes split down to the decimal and the electors split as many ways as there are candidates. There are downsides to this system though, including 1) that fractions and decimals must be acceptable and used and 2) the vote count must be precise so states will be required to expend time and resources verifying the vote count so the electoral votes can be split appropriately. At the same time, he observes that this system can produce winners that are inconsistent with the statewide popular vote and the winner under this system may still not reflect the national popular vote winner (i.e. the national popular vote winner may still lose the electoral vote and thus still lose the presidency). That being said, Fon also acknowledges that under any Electoral College system model, it is possible for the winner of the electoral vote to lose the popular vote. There has also been a movement to adopt ranked choice voting in state and federal races, including the race for president. In ranked choice voting, voters rank candidates in 14 order of their preference. They mark their most preferred candidate with a 1, their second most preferred candidate with a 2, and so on down the list of candidates. If one candidate gets the majority of first place votes, that candidate wins. If no candidate reaches that threshold, the candidate with the least first place votes is eliminated, and all of those votes are reallocated to their second pick. This process continues until one candidate has received the majority of votes and/or only two candidates remain. Richie (2017) argues that ranked choice voting provides new incentives for candidates to reach out to all voters, rather than just their base, in an effort to obtain a higher ranking. He also argues that it can “mitigate partisan inflexibility, foster greater accountability for incumbents, increase civic engagement, and reduce the impact of campaign spending” (Richie 2017, 20). He also discusses ranked choice voting as a realistic alternative to utilizing run-offs due to the issues of disparate turnout in run-offs compared to the general election. He notes that more than 96% of the 200 congressional primary run-offs since 1994 experienced declines in turnout, with the turnout decline averaging more than 30%. Ranked choice voting acts as an instant run-off with the vote re-allocation mechanism, thus ensuring that there are no voter turnout disparities between the general election and the run-off. Santucci (2018) argues that ranked choice voting is likely to find positive support when three conditions are met: (1) a spoiler is present, (2) most voters prefer the losing, major party to its main alternative, and (3) the losing, major party knows this. Initiatives to implement ranked choice voting sprang up in states and cities around the country after the 2000 election, when Ralph Nader took enough votes from Al Gore (D) to deprive him of a plurality in Florida and thus the election. 15 This method of voting is proposed not only to ensure that the winning candidate receives majority support from their constituents and accommodates an election having more than two candidates, but also because it limits, if not totally removes, the impacts of spoiler candidates. According to Poundstone (2008), spoiler candidates “can take enough votes from one of the front-runners to hand the election to his rival” (20). Elections with spoilers tend to be highly controversial (election of 2000) and usually see one of the major parties assisting the minor candidate. As noted by Poundstone, the Republican Party in 2000 lent support to Ralph Nader in a bid to boost Bush and hurt Gore, and again, the GOP tried to get him to run again in 2004 in an effort to hurt Democratic nominee John Kerry and help Bush get re-elected. Another form of voting that has been part of reform discussions is approval voting. Under this method of voting, voters select as many candidates as they choose, with each vote for each candidate carrying equal weight. In effect, they are selecting which candidates they approve of being president, while not selecting those they wish not to see win. Approval voting has been adopted by many issue-oriented associations, such as the Mathematical Association of America and the Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers, and has been used in the 1980s in competitive elections in Eastern Europe and the Soviet Union. Some U.S. states also attempted to pass approval voting in statewide elections in the late 1980s, but none passed. Brams and Fishburn (2005) present six arguments in favor of the implementation of approval voting: (1) gives voters more flexibility, (2) helps elect the strongest candidate, (3) reduce negative campaigning, (4) increase voter turnout, (5) 16 give minority candidates their “proper due,” and (6) eminently practical. Approval voting, according to Brams and Fishburn, would enable minority (third party or independent) candidates to obtain their true support because voters could still vote for them and they could vote for the major candidate that they feel best represents them, so they can still vote for their true preference while still having a say in the outcome either way. Smith, Quintal, and Greene (2005) argue that implementing approval voting could result in three potential benefits: (1) immunity to clones, (2) more chance of getting a result you like, and (3) less worrying about strategy and more about your honest opinion. They argue that vote splitting is less likely to occur because if multiple candidates are similar and appeal to the same group of voters, they can simply cast a vote for each rather than having to select just one. This also gives voters a greater chance that a candidate they prefer will win, thus further incentivizing them to vote and vote honestly. Nagel (2007) argues, however, that a form of approval voting was used in the first four presidential elections and culminated in the election of 1800 debacle, where Jefferson and Burr tied in the electoral vote and the U.S. House subsequently took thirty-six votes to finally elect Jefferson, what he calls the “Burr Dilemma.” He presents three scenarios that he argues undermine the potential benefits of approval voting. The first scenario is that should voters on a large scale decide not to vote for two candidates and only vote for one candidate, the system has broken down back into the system it was designed and implemented to replace. The second scenario is that should voters vote for two candidates who are similar in ideology and policy positions that were courting the same voters, there is a real possibility that those two candidates could tie, 17 throwing the election to the U.S. House as it did in 1800. The third scenario he presents is that to avoid a tie, candidates and their followers would be tempted to defect from any explicit or implicit agreement to share votes. This final scenario, as it did between Jefferson and Burr in 1796 and 1800, can lead to increasing divisions and mistrusts within the members of one party and could undermine future collaborations. Range voting (also referred to as score voting) has also been a topic of discussion. This system of voting works similarly to how rating a movie works: on their ballot, the voter awards each candidate running a score on a scale of 0-5, with 5 being the top score and 0 being the lowest. The candidate with the best average score is the winner of the election. Smith, Quintal, and Greene (2005) argue that range voting would provide two potential benefits: (1) more voter expressivity and (2) more voter interest, higher turnout. According to them, with more ability to express themselves, voters will be more interested in submitting their ballot. With more choices and more ability to fully express themselves, voters potentially may turn out in higher numbers to vote. They also argue that because the range voting ballot provides more information that the current plurality ballot or an approval voting ballot would ensure that better candidates will be elected. Voter turnout is an issue in American politics. Turnout in elections lags behind every other Western democracy in the world. Gerber and Green (2000) argue that declining turnout rates are the result of the evolution of modern American campaigns. They argue that campaigns increasingly using impersonal methods of mobilization (telephone calls, direct mail) has resulted in voter turnout declining. They conducted an experiment to test their hypothesis and found that canvassing in-person rather than over 18 the phone or sending mail raises the probability of turnout by 8.7%, with a standard error of 2.6. Richey (2008) examined the institutional barriers theory, using Oregon as a case study, which states that complicated voting procedures make turnout difficult, so less people vote. Using data from presidential elections from 1980 through 2004, and mid-term elections from 1982-2006, he used a cross-sectional time-series (CXTS) regression model of aggregate state-level turnout data to determine the effects of voting by mail. Oregon adopted universal vote-by-mail in time for the 2000 presidential election and has used it since. The results of his test indicated a significant positive effect from voting by mail that came out to be about 10 points of registered voters in both mid-term and presidential elections. Richie (2017) argues that ranked choice voting has the potential to increase voter turnout in any election it is implemented for. Data analysis from more than 125 ranked choice voting elections in the Bay Area found that voter turnout on average has risen sharply from prior systems that used primaries and runoffs. Brams and Fishburn (2005) argue that by implementing approval voting, voters will be more likely to vote because they will be able to better express their preferences. They also believe that voters will have an easier time voting if they are undecided between multiple candidates or feel they are wasting their vote because they can vote for multiple candidates and are not forced to make a single choice. Voters could feel that the system enables them to be more honest, and that has the potential to make voting more meaningful and help increase turnout. 19 Research Methods The literature on the Electoral College and prior research I have conducted were consulted heavily when determining which electoral allocation reforms should be tested. The proportional and Maine-Nebraska congressional district methods were reviewed once again, after having previously evaluating these using the 2000, 2004, 2008, 2012, and 2016 elections1. These were chosen because the Maine-Nebraska method is already used in those states for presidential elections and seeing how it would work nationwide is of interest amongst political scientists. The other methods discussed would also account for votes cast by the minority party and third parties. Ranked choice voting is utilized in Maine for their elections and has been proposed in Maine and other states to be used in presidential elections. Approval and range voting, as well as ranked choice, provide more viability to minor and third-party candidates and thus provide additional options to voters. Approval voting is also the method used by the UN to elect the Secretary-General. A survey was written to gather the relevant data for the new voting systems being tested as well as inquiring about voters’ opinions on electoral reform and turnout. Respondents were asked to identify their age from the following options: 18-25, 26-35, 36-45, 46-55, 56-65, and 66+; they were asked to identify their sex from the following options: male, female, and other; and they were asked to select their political party identification from the following options: Democratic Party, Republican Party, Libertarian Party, Green Party, Independent, Other. The proportional method will be evaluated again for the 2020 election for this paper assuming the FEC report is released in time. 1 20 After gathering demographic information, respondents were presented with a ballot that had the same options as the 2020 Pennsylvania presidential election ballot: Joseph R. Biden/Kamala D. Harris (Democratic), Donald J. Trump/Michael R. Pence (Republican), and Jo Jorgensen/Jeremy “Spike” Cohen (Libertarian). Respondents were asked to rank each ticket as either “Most Preferred,” “Second Preferred,” or “Least Preferred.” They were then asked to select the presidential tickets that they would approve of being president, with the note that they were allowed to select more than one ticket. They then were asked to score each ticket on a scale from 0-5, with 5 being the best score and 0 being the worst score. Respondents then were asked if changing how we elect the president would make them more likely, less likely, or if there would be no change in likelihood of their participation in presidential elections. The final question asked them to select their preferred electoral model for electing the president from the following options: Electoral College, national popular vote, proportional allocation, congressional district model, ranked choice voting, approval voting, range (score) voting, and other. The traditional method of electoral vote allocation served as the control in this experimental simulation. It operated the way the current Electoral College works, and the results were as they were in those election years. The popular method uses the national popular vote to award the presidency. Whichever candidate won the most votes nationwide was elected president in this simulation. In the proportional method of electoral vote allocation, votes were awarded based on the proportion of the vote received by each candidate. Leftover votes that no candidate earned were not awarded to any candidate. The congressional district model of electoral vote allocation followed the 21 model currently in use by Maine and Nebraska. Candidates received an electoral vote each congressional district won in that state. Whichever candidate won the popular vote in that state was awarded the final two electoral votes. Data and Results Figure 1. Age of participants by percentage Figure 2. Participants' sex by percentage 4.40%2.90% 1.30% 18-25 17.50% 23.60% 26-35 51.50% Female 36-45 Male 46-55 Other 56-65 14.30% 66+ 75.20% 9.80% Figure 3. Participants' political party affiliation by percentage 12.80% 3.20% Democratic 0% 2.90% Republican Libertarian 21.70% 59.40% Green Independent Other 22 System Winner Electoral College National Popular Vote Proportional Allocation Ranked Choice Voting Range (Score) Voting Approval Voting Biden Biden Biden Biden Biden Biden Table 1. 2020 Presidential Election Results Under Alternative Voting Systems Figure 5. Participant preferences for alternative voting systems Figure 4. Likelihood of participant participation in presidential election if the electoral system is reformed 21.30% 5.10% 73.70% More Likely Less Likely No Change In Likelihood Electoral College National Popular Vote Proportional Allocation Congressional District Model Ranked Choice Voting Approval Voting Range (Score) Voting Other Figure 6. Likelihood of respondents voting in presidential elections if the electoral college is reformed by party affiliation 90.00% 80.00% 70.00% 60.00% 50.00% 40.00% 30.00% 20.00% 10.00% 0.00% Democratic Republican No Change in Likelihood Libertarian More Likely Independent Other Less Likely 23 Figure 7. Electoral reform preferences by party Other Range (Score) Voting Approval Voting Ranked Choice Voting Congressional District Model Proportional Allocation National Popular Vote Electoral College 0.00% Other 10.00% Independent 20.00% 30.00% Libertarian 40.00% Republican 50.00% 60.00% 70.00% Democratic Conclusions and Discussion In total, the sample size (n) of survey respondents was 316. Demographically, respondents represented every age, sex, and party category with the exception of the Green Party. Respondents largely identified as female and Democratic, and the majority were in the youngest generation (age 18-25). As demonstrated by Table 1, now President Joe Biden would have won the 2020 presidential election under all electoral systems tested in the survey. The Electoral College method (how it is currently conducted and thus acts as the control for this survey) results in former Vice President Joe Biden winning 306 electoral votes (thirtysix votes more than the required 270) over incumbent President Donald Trump’s 232 electoral votes. The National Popular Vote also gives Biden a victory with a margin of 24 7,052,770 votes. Awarding votes by proportional allocation shows a much tighter race, but still with Joe Biden winning. Under this system, he would have received 273 electoral votes (three more than is required) to then President Donald Trump’s 255 electoral votes. Biden also would have won under ranked choice voting, with 221 respondents (approximately 70%) ranking the Biden-Harris ticket as their number 1 choice, with seventy-nine respondents (approximately 25%) ranking the Trump-Pence ticket as their number 2 choice. Because the Biden-Harris ticket received the majority of first place votes, a run-off would not occur, and they would be declared the winner. The Biden-Harris ticket would also emerge victorious under range (score) voting. Under this system, the Biden- Harris ticket would receive a score of 3.37, compared to the Trump-Pence ticket’s score of 1.43. It is worth noting that this system also saw the Libertarian ticket, Jorgensen-Cohen, receive a higher score than the Trump-Pence ticket. Their ticket wins a score of 1.71. Finally, the Biden- Harris ticket wins under approval voting as well, with 235 (approximately 76.1%) respondents stating that they would approve of Biden being president, compared to eighty-nine (approximately 28.8%) respondents that selected Trump. The Libertarian ticket also made significant headway in this system as well, with sixty-five (approximately 21%) respondents either selecting just Jorgensen-Cohen or selecting them with at least one of the major party tickets. I hypothesized that electoral reform would not produce results different from the control (the Electoral College), and these results support that hypothesis. Respondents were also asked questions about their participation in presidential elections. As seen in Figure 4, a supermajority of respondents (73.7%) indicate that electoral reform would not change their likelihood of participating in presidential 25 elections, with 21.3% saying electoral reform would make them more likely to participate and 5.1% saying electoral reform would make them less likely to participate. A supermajority is considered either 2/3 (approximately 67%) or 3/5 (approximately 60%), depending on the setting. Due to the large number of respondents stating that electoral reform would not change their likelihood of participating but a smaller percentage stating that it would make them more likely, it is possible that voter turnout could see a small increase depending on how the Electoral College were reformed. This also indicates that electoral reform is not a driving factor in voter turnout in presidential elections. If it were, we would expect that significantly more respondents would have chosen the “more likely” option. This pattern holds true by party identification as well. As seen in figure 6, respondents of all party identifications indicate that electoral reform would result in no change in likelihood of participating in presidential elections. The Libertarians at 66.7% had the smallest number of respondents that chose “no change in likelihood.” This means that other variables and other possibilities should be explored in more depth to pinpoint the major factors that depress turnout. This data does support my hypothesis that electoral reform would increase turnout. With 5.1% of respondents saying they would be less likely to participate in presidential elections and 21.3% of respondents saying electoral reform would make them more likely to participate, that leaves the potential for a net increase in turnout of 16.2%. This of course does not mean, as stated before but should be reiterated, that turnout would increase as other factors are likely at play that depress turnout and would likely need resolved before seeing substantial turnout increases. Preferences for voting systems are more diverse and show that Americans are more split on what the best way is for electing the president than originally expected. A 26 slight majority, as can be seen in figure 5, favor abolition of the Electoral College and the implementation of a national popular vote (52.1%). The remaining 47.9% of respondents were extremely divided over which electoral system they preferred, with the Electoral College coming in second with 18.5% and ranked choice voting coming in third with 16%. Breaking it down by party shows some interesting patterns as well. When evaluating the results for the national popular vote, all represented parties exceed 40.00% support, however only Democrats, Independents, and Other reach or surpass 50.00% support (Republican support comes in at 44.1% and Libertarian support comes in at 44.4%). A similar pattern emerges with preferences by party for the Electoral College, where neither Democrats nor Independents reach 20.0% support (15.2% and 7.7%, respectively), while both Republicans and Libertarians exceed 20.0% support (36.8% and 22.2% respectively). Democrats and Independents tend to be closer in agreement while Republicans and Libertarians tend to be closer in agreement on this issue. This pattern holds true for all electoral systems tested with the exception of ranked choice voting, where Democrats, Libertarians, and Independents all reach or exceed 10.0% support, and Republicans fall short of that support threshold, and range (score) voting, where Libertarian support exceeds 10.0%, but no other party affiliation reaches that threshold. Overall, regardless of party affiliation, respondents are divided over electoral system preferences, with the greatest support from all party affiliations falling under the national popular vote, thus the data supports my hypothesis that the national popular vote would be the most preferred option. 27 Future Research Additional research that could be conducted would go more in depth with the voter turnout aspect of this study. An important step for future research would include a survey question asking about their participation in presidential elections under the current system. Determining whether respondents are regular voters, semi-regular voters, or non-regular voters could provide greater insight into how different variables influence whether someone shows up at the polls or not. An expansion on respondents’ preferences could also be beneficial by determining which electoral system would make them more likely, less likely, or have no change in their likelihood of participating in presidential elections. As mentioned earlier, voter turnout over the last century has been on the decline. Additional research that could add on to this study could also ask respondents why they are regular, semi-regular, or non-regular voters. Inquiring about why semi-regular and non-regular voters do not vote regularly would also give greater insights into the decline in voter turnout and what can be done to reverse that trend. Topics that could be tested include policy questions, political polarization, ballot options and/or format, or leaving it as an open-ended question so respondents could explain on their own and then the researcher could look for patterns as to why Americans do not regularly vote or do not vote at all. 28 References Aldrich, J., Reifler, J., and Munger, M. (2014). Sophisticated and Myopic? Citizen Preferences for Electoral College Reform. Public Choice. Vol. 158, p. 541-558. Brams, S. J., & Fishburn, P. C. (2005). Going from theory to practice: the mixed success of approval voting. Social Choice & Welfare, 25(2/3), p. 457–474. Cain, C; Basciano, P; Cain, E. (2007). The Electoral College: Diversification and the Election Process. Springer Science and Business Media. Vol. 18, p. 21-34. DeSilver, D. (2020). In past elections, U.S. trailed most developed countries in voter turnout. Retrieved December 02, 2020, from https://www.pewresearch.org/facttank/2020/11/03/in-past- elections-u-s-trailed-most-developed-countries-in-voterturnout/ Drake, I, J. (2013). Federal Roadblocks: The Constitution and the National Popular Vote Interstate Compact. The Journal of Federalism, 44(4), p. 681-701. FEC (Federal Election Commission). 2017. “Federal Elections 2016: Election Results for the U.S. President, the U.S. Senate, and the U.S. House of Representatives.” Florey, K. (2017). Losing Bargain: Why the Winner-Take-All Vote Assignment is the Electoral College’s Least Defensible Feature. Case Western Reserve Law Review. Vol. 68, p. 317-395. Foley, E. B. (2020). Presidential Elections and Majority Rule: The Rise, Demise, and Potential Restoration of the Jeffersonian Electoral College. New York, NY: Oxford University Press. Fon, V. (2004). Electoral College Alternatives and US Presidential Elections. Supreme Court Economic Review, Vol. 12, p. 41-73. Gerber, A.S. & Green, D.J. (2000). The Effects of Canvassing, Telephone Calls, and Direct Mail on Voter Turnout: A Field Experiment. The American Political Science Review, Vol. 94, No. 3. p. 653-663. Issacharoff, S. (2005). Law, Rules, and Presidential Selection. Political Science Quarterly (Academy of Political Science), 120(1), p. 113–129. Karp, J; Tolbert, C. (2010). Polls and Elections: Support for Nationalizing Presidential Elections. Nagel, J. H. (2007). The Burr Dilemma in Approval Voting. Journal of Politics, 69(1), p. 43–58. 29 Nardulli, Peter; Dalager, Jon; Greco, Donald. (1996). Voter Turnout n U.S. Presidential Elections. Political Science and Politics, Vol. 29, No. 3, p. 480-490. Pavia, J. M. (2011). On Introducing Proportionality in American Presidential Elections: An Historical Analysis, 1828-2008. The Political Quarterly, 82(3), p. 435-447. Poundstone, C. (2008). Gaming the Vote: Why Elections Aren’t Fair (and What We Can Do About It). Douglas & McIntyre Ltd. Ratcliffe, D. (2014). Popular Preferences in the Presidential Election of 1824. Journal of the Early Republic, 34(1), p. 45–77. Richey, S. (2008). Voting by Mail: Turnout and Institutional Reform in Oregon. Social Science Quarterly. Vol. 89, No. 4. p. 902-915. Richie, R., Levien, A. (2013). The Contemporary Presidency: How the 2012 Presidential Election Has Strengthened the Movement for the National Popular Vote Plan. Presidential Studies Quarterly 43, no. 2, p. 353-376. Richie, R. (2017). National Implications of Maine Adoption of Ranked Choice Voting. National Civic Review, p. 20-24. Santucci, J. (2018). Maine Ranked Choice Voting as a Case of Electoral System Change. Representation: Journal of Representative Democracy, Vol 54, No. 3, p. 297-311. Schropp, J. (2010). The Great Compromiser: James A. Bayard and the Election of 1800. Delaware History, 33(2), p. 97–121. Smith, W.D, Quintal, J.N, & Greene, D.S. (2005) What if the 2004 US presidential election had been held using Range or Approval voting. p. 1-17. Turner, R. (2005). The Contemporary Presidency: Do Nebraska and Maine Have the Right Idea? The Political and Partisan Implications of the District System. Presidential Studies Quarterly 35, no. 1, p. 116-137. Weinschenk, A. C., & Panagopoulos, C. (2018). The Dynamics of Voter Preferences in the 2016 Presidential Election. Forum (2194-6183), 16(1), p. 123–135. Yale Law School. 2008. U.S. Constitution. The Avalon Project. https://avalon.law.yale.edu/18th_century/usconst.asp 30